European Union and New Regionalism
40
Standard trade theory gives a precise answer to the question of number: the optimal
size of a trade agreement is the world. Short of full liberalization, however, partial
elimination of barriers following integration will generally improve the allocation
of resources and welfare. Although the welfare gain might be partially curtailed
by trade diversion, which could offset gains from trade creation, reallocation of
resources generated by the integration process allows the exploitation of national
comparative advantages. Differences in national resource endowments will lead
to a deepening of specialization patterns which will benefit all countries involved
in the integration process. Factors of production will be allocated in sectors where
the country enjoys a comparative advantage, while production in other sectors
will stop or be reduced. The process will, of course, involve adjustment costs and
temporary unemployment, the severity and duration of which could be alleviated by
appropriate financial support. Once reallocation is completed, inter-industry trade,
that is, trade in goods belonging to different sectors (for example, textiles and food
products), within the region will increase. Note that the benefits of integration, in
such a framework, could be equally obtained by the reallocation of factors among
countries, that is, by migration and/or capital movements.
Within traditional trade theory the reason why the organization of international
trade falls short of global liberalization is usually found in the presence of special
interests that, given imperfect political markets, have the resources and the ability
to obtain protection from national or regional governments.
‘New trade theory’ has pointed at another possible source of gains from
integration, deriving from the exploitation of (static and dynamic) gains from trade.
7
The larger market generated by integration allows (oligopolistic) firms to exploit
increasing returns. This leads to further specialization within the same sectors, as
competition rests both on lower costs deriving from expanded production and on
product (quality) differentiation. Intra-industry trade, that is, trade of similar goods
between countries, will be generated. Welfare gains from integration will ensue
from lower costs and broader quality range as well as the exploitation of dynamic
returns to scale generated by the learning process following the introduction of new
technologies. In this case, too, costs could arise from integration; however, they
would be permanent, rather than temporary. In addition to the standard adjustment
costs, economies of scale could generate agglomeration effects as both capital and
labour would concentrate in specific areas, leading to permanent core–periphery
effects within the region. Employment opportunities would concentrate in some
areas, exacerbating the asymmetrical distribution of net benefits (Krugman, 1993).
In general, trade integration would increase both inter- and intra-industry
trade and, in both cases, increased competition would activate pressures to resist
adjustment and/or demand for compensatory measures on the part of countries and
regions most severely hit by the asymmetric distribution of net benefits.
The emergence of inequalities generated by the process of integration raises
the issue of ‘cohesion’, which may be defined as ‘[a principle that] implies … a
relatively equal social and territorial distribution of employment opportunities, of
wealth and of income, and of improvements in the quality of life that correspond to
increasing expectations’ (Smith and Tsoukalis, 1996: 1). An important implication
is that, without cohesion, political support for a regional agreement is likely to
fail.