Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
P1: GDZ
0521812909c14BCB929-Bulmer 052181290 9 October 6, 2005 14:6
638 Miguel Sz
´
ekely and Andr
´
es Montes
endowments by computing each country’s share in world trade and mul-
tiplying this share by the factor endowment (human capital, physical cap-
ital, and land) to obtain a trade-weighted average.
33
The weights are used
because the factor endowments of a country only compete in the world
market if the country actually trades. Therefore, endowments of countries
totally closed to international trade have no weight in the average, whereas
those that do trade are weighted by their importance in international
markets.
34
trade and human capital endowments
The story of the evolution of human capital is illustrated in Figure 14.16,
which plots the endowment of the most unskilled labor available for pro-
duction – that is, the share of workers with no schooling among the pop-
ulation over twenty-five years of age.
35
As can be seen, Latin America has a
much larger share of working-age population with no schooling than the
East Asian economies or the world average but has a considerably lower
share than South Asia, the most populous region in the world.
33
These authors estimate country and world endowments up to 1992.Here we update the figures to
1996.Weuse the same estimation methods and (updated) data sources as these authors.
34
There are some other studies addressing the trade–inequality relationship. Francois Bourgignon
and C. Morrison, eds., External Trade and Income Distribution (Paris, 1989), develop a model in
which income distribution depends on factor endowments and the degree of trade openness of each
country. By using a cross-country analysis of thirty-six observations in 1970, they conclude that
factor endowments can explain 60 percent of the difference in income shares of the bottom decile
across countries. Sebastian Edwards, “Openness, Trade Liberalization and Growth in Developing
Countries,” Journal of Economic Literature 31 (1997): 1358–93, uses a larger sample of countries with
time-series observations, but does not find any significant effect of trade on income distribution.
There is a larger number of studies addressing the trade–wage inequality relationship. For example,
see Donald Robbins, “HOS Hits Facts: Facts Win: Evidence on Trade and Wages in the Developing
World” (Development Discussion Paper 557,Harvard Institute for International Development,
Harvard University, 1996); Adrian Wood, North-South Trade Employment and Inequality: Changing
Fortunes in a Skill-Driven World, (London, 1994), and “Openness and Wage Inequality in Developing
Countries: The Latin American Challenge to East Asian Conventional Wisdom,” The World Bank
Economic Review (1996); George Borjas and Valerie Ramey, “Foreign Competition, Market Power
and Wage Inequalities,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics XC (1995): 1075–1110; Richard Freeman
and Lawrence Katz, eds., Differences and Changes in Wage Structure (Chicago, 1995). We chose the
methodology by Spilimbergo, Londo
˜
no, and Sz
´
ekely for two reasons. The first is that they use
more adequate trade openness measure and estimation methods, and the second is that rather than
focusing on wage inequality, they consider the distribution of total household income.
35
These figures use the share of adults with no schooling, primary, secondary, and higher education
from the updated Barro-Lee database. See Jong Wha Lee and Robert Barro, “International Data on
Educational Attainment: Updates and Implications,” (Working Paperno.42, Center for International
Development, Harvard University, April 2000)tomeasure the human capital endowment of each
country. East Asia, according to the definition adopted here, comprises the four fastest growing East
Asian countries.