
Linear Equations
104
To conclude this section we return to the simple two-sector model:
Y = C + I
C = aY + b
Previously, the investment, I, was taken to be constant. It is more realistic to assume that
planned investment depends on the rate of interest, r. As the interest rate rises, so investment
falls and we have a relationship
I = cr + d
where c < 0 and d > 0. Unfortunately, this model consists of three equations in the four
unknowns Y, C, I and r, so we cannot expect it to determine national income uniquely. The
best we can do is to eliminate C and I, say, and to set up an equation relating Y and r. This is
most easily understood by an example. Suppose that
C = 0.8Y + 100
I =−20r + 1000
We know that the commodity market is in equilibrium when
Y = C + I
Substitution of the given expressions for C and I into this equation gives
Y = (0.8Y + 100) + (−20r + 1000)
= 0.8Y − 20r + 1100
which rearranges as
0.2Y + 20r = 1100
This equation, relating national income, Y, and interest rate, r, is called the IS schedule.
We obviously need some additional information before we can pin down the values of Y
and r. This can be done by investigating
the equilibrium of the money market. The
money market is said to be in equilibrium
when the supply of money, M
S
, matches
the demand for money, M
D
: that is, when
M
S
= M
D
There are many ways of measuring the
money supply. In simple terms it can be
thought of as consisting of the notes and
coins in circulation, together with money
held in bank deposits. The level of M
S
is
assumed to be controlled by the central
bank and is taken to be autonomous,
so that
M
S
= M*
S
for some fixed value M*
S
.
The demand for money comes from
three sources: transactions, precautions and
speculations. The transactions demand is
used for the daily exchange of goods and
MFE_C01f.qxd 16/12/2005 10:58 Page 104