
susanne lohmann 531
Government spending continues to be loaded with special interest pork. For ex-
ample, in response to 11 September, Congress appropriated huge amounts of money
to homeland security, and then promptly distributed the money according to the
principles of pork-barrel politics. Thus, states get money not based on risk and vul-
nerability considerations, but based on population and state minimums. Wyoming,
which is hardly in the sights of worldwide terrorist networks, gets seven times as many
homeland security dollars, on a per capita basis, than does New York. Once again,
the political logic is perfectly well understood, even the subject of a New York Times
editorial, and yet nothing, apparently, can be done about it (New York Times 2005).
Let us continue with the 11 September theme and take a look at Joe Barton, who
in 2005 chaired the House Energy and Commerce Committee. He used his clout to
block chemical plant security legislation. Chemical plants are vulnerable to terrorist
attacks. Two of the most dangerous facilities are located in Dallas, right next to
Barton’s district. They constitute a risk for more than one million people. A Texas
Republican, Barton sides with the energy industry at the expense of his constituents—
and forget about the constituents of his colleagues in Congress. Barton is the classical
“high demander” on a congressional committee: before he was elected to Congress,
he served as a consultant for an oil and gas company, and he has received more than
$1.8 million in campaign contributions from the energy and chemical industries.
Once again, the political logic is perfectly well understood, even the subject of a New
Yo rk Tim es editorial, and yet nothing, apparently, can be done about it (Cohen 2005).
Looking back, one cannot help wondering whether public choice, with its insis-
tence on simple and transparent institutions that might actually help slay the special
interest dragon, had something important going on that got lost when political econ-
omy insisted on deriving ever more elaborate “optimal” institutions in a reductionist
framework including hyper-rationality and equilibrium-über-Alles.
Next, take the developing countries. Today, in 2005, China stands out as the
country with the largest population, ahead of India, and the second-largest economy,
after the United States. In the last twenty-five years, after the Communist leadership
embarked on a course of economic liberalization, China’s real GDP increased close to
eightfold, its real GDP per capita close to sixfold. This increase, with its speed and size,
along with the huge number of people involved, has got to count as the single largest
explosion in standards of living in human history. Several hundred million people
were lifted out of the poverty of living on (the purchasing-power-parity equivalent
of) one dollar a day, and some got very rich.
The nagging question is why China has outperformed India, which—in contrast
to China—is a democracy. But if India is politically liberal, economically it is not; or
rather, it was not until recently when it, too, caught the economic liberalization bug,
no doubt in response to China’s glowing success. After independence in 1947, India
pursued policies that reflected a philosophy of government planning and economic
self-sufficiency. Its economy was relatively stagnant until piecemeal economic reforms
in the 1980s and some measure of economic liberalization in the 1990simproved
economic growth rates. Today, in the 2000s, India appears poised for a take-off that
might well end up outperforming China’s.