
would involve duplication of mains, track and related networks, quite apart from
any savings that arose from concentrating production itself in large electricity
generating plants or gas works. Since there were few substitutes for these services
(‘necessities’) the potential for monopoly profits was large. Other basic economic
problems were present – spillover effects in health from poor water supplies or
leaky gas mains or unsafe trams. But the natural monopoly argument threads
through all narratives of the development of utilities in the nineteenth century
and is usually accompanied by the prediction that competition either leads to
duplicate facilities, high costs, low profits and poor service or it leads to monop-
oly. ‘In the s and s it was common for the mains of three or four . . .
[gas] . . . companies to run down the same street in the West End.’
9
David
Chatterton, Malcolm Falkus and William Robson argued that, when this led
eventually to the elimination of competition, a change in public opinion
occurred and promoted the growth of parliamentary involvement in these
sectors.
10
Derek Matthews demurred, suggesting that parliament always had the
power to regulate and became more active from the middle of the century
because by then gas prices had fallen sufficiently to allow gas lighting in middle-
class homes – as well as in the houses and factories of the highest income
groups.
11
This new vociferous middle-class customer clamoured for control of
prices especially when their decline slowed from mid-century. If true, that
incentive always probably existed for water customers from the beginning of the
century. The evidence is patchy but it appears that the average costs and prices
of, for example the London water companies, rose by about per cent in the
period to when most other prices in Britain were falling.
12
In fact there are good reasons for thinking that whilst the underlying eco-
nomics of utilities are such that laissez-faire is often not consistent with the public
interest, this still left a wide range of possible reactions and collective interven-
tions. Whereas in France, Prussia and Belgium network systems like the railways
were planned, in Britain the outcome was more the result of a battle of prop-
erty interests.
13
The manufacturers of gas and the waterworks entrepreneurs
wanted no truck with government. Nor was the weight of opinion in parlia-
Robert Millward
19
See p. of D. Matthews, ‘Rogues, speculators and competing monopolies: the early London gas
companies, –’, London Journal, (), –.
10
D. A. Chatterton, ‘State control of public utilities in the nineteenth century: the London gas
industry’, Business History, (), –; M. Falkus, ‘The development of municipal trading
in the nineteenth century’, Business History, (), –; W. A. Robson, ‘The public utility
services’, in H. J. Laski, W. I. Jennings and W. A. Robson, eds., A Century of Municipal Progress:
The Last One Hundred Years (London, ), pp. –.
11
D. Matthews, ‘Laissez-faire and the London gas industry in the nineteenth century: another look’,
Ec.HR, nd series, (), –.
12
See later discussion of water and also J. Cavalcanti, ‘Economic aspects of the provision and devel-
opment of water supply in nineteenth century Britain’ (PhDThesis, Manchester University,
).
13
F. Dobbin, Forging Industrial Policy (Cambridge, ).
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008