
development through a large landed estate and undesirable irregularity elsewhere
became less prominent.
In north Leeds agricultural estate owners rarely engaged in building estate
development after , and even before this date the prevalence of freehold
tenure meant that land was often sold for development.
23
Several large estates
made attempts to let land on other tenures, but competition from rival develop-
ers meant that prospective purchasers were usually able to insist on freehold
tenure. Similarly, the Ramsden estate in Huddersfield, despite its large size and
strategic position in the town, was unable to impose year leases in the s
and had to adopt year leases instead.
24
By contrast, there was always a ready
market for freehold land even in towns dominated by leasehold tenure. It would
appear therefore that leasehold tenure needed to be established under conditions
in which competition from freehold could be controlled. This was most likely
to be the case early in urban development, and the notable contrasts between
major English cities in the nature of their tenure were clearly evident in the late
eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries.
25
In Scotland, certainly, a distinctive
tenure, the feuing system, was already established which contrasted with the
English types. Richard Rodger’s attempt to link this feature to the particular
form and density of Scottish towns constitutes perhaps the most notable attempt
in recent literature to preserve a strong role for supply factors in the complex
interaction of causes affecting urban development.
26
Despite the fact that, according to Jane Springett, the Ramsden estate was
‘brought to heel’ by the petite bourgeoisie in the s, it none the less had a dis-
cernible impact on the town through the controls exerted over the development
of the estate. The result was that a lesser proportion of lower-class property was
built, but to some extent at least at the expense of higher rents and greater
crowding of dwellings than in neighbouring towns. Elsewhere, too, large estates
were frequently associated, other things being equal, with higher-value residen-
tial property, while the reverse was true on fragmented lands. Even in the East
End of London large estates such as the Mercers were able to some extent to
shape their own market.
27
They were able to do so because of the quality of the
initial building, and because of the controls that were exercised over tenancy and
land use. Clearly, controlled development could not transcend the larger effects
of class or income, and beyond a certain point insistence on high-quality build-
ing led to rents which suppressed demand and resulted in housing problems
Land, property and planning
23
C. Treen, ‘The process of suburban development in north Leeds –’, in F. M. L.
Thompson, ed., The Rise of Suburbia (Leicester ), pp. –.
24
Springett, ‘Land development’, p. .
25
C. W. Chalklin, The Provincial Towns of Georgian England (London, ); C. W. Chalklin, ‘Urban
housing estates in the eighteenth century’, Urban Studies, (), –.
26
Rodger, ‘Rents and ground rents’, pp. –.
27
M. Paton, ‘Corporate East End landlords: the example of the London Hospital and the Mercers
Company’, LJ, (), –.
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008