
408
PART II
✦
Generalized Regression Model and Equation Systems
There is yet another direction that we might extend this estimation method. In
(11-76), we have implicitly allowed a more general covariance matrix to govern the
generation of the disturbances ε
it
and computed a robust covariance matrix for the
simple IV estimator. We could take this a step further and look for a more efficient
estimator. As a library of recent studies has shown, panel data sets are rich in information
that allows the analyst to specify highly general models and to exploit the implied
relationships among the variables to construct much more efficient generalized method
of moments (GMM) estimators. [See, in particular, Arellano and Bover (1995) and
Blundell and Bond (1998).] We will return to this development in Chapter 13.
Example 11.15 Dynamic Labor Supply Equation
In Example 8.5, we used instrumental variables fit a labor supply equation,
Wks
it
= γ
1
+ γ
2
ln Wage
it
+ γ
3
Ed
i
+ γ
4
Union
it
+ γ
5
Fem
i
+ u
it
.
To illustrate the computations of this section, we will extend this model as follows:
Wks
it
= β
1
In Wage
it
+ β
2
Union
it
+ β
3
Occ
it
+ β
4
Exp
it
+ δ Wks
i,t−1
+α + γ
1
Ed
i
+ γ
2
Fem
i
+ c
i
+ ε
it
.
(We have rearranged the variables and parameter names to conform to the notation in this
section.) We note, in theoretical terms, as suggested in the earlier example, it may not be
appropriate to treat ln Wage
it
as uncorrelated with ε
it
or c
i
. However, we will be analyzing the
model in first differences. It may well be appropriate to treat changes in wages as exogenous.
That would depend on the theoretical underpinnings of the model. We will treat the variable
as predetermined here, and proceed. There are two time-invariant variables in the model,
Fem
i
, which is clearly exogenous, and Ed
i
, which might be endogenous. The identification
requirement for estimation of ( α, γ
1
, γ
2
) is met by the presence of three exogenous variables,
Union
it
, Occ
it
, and Exp
it
(K
1
= 3 and L
2
= 1).
The differenced equation analyzed at the first step is
Wks
it
= β
1
In Wage
it
+ β
2
Union
it
+ β
3
Occ
it
+ β
4
Exp
it
+ δWks
i,t−1
+ ε
it
.
We estimated the parameters and the asymptotic covariance matrix according to (11-72) and
(11-76). For specification of the instrumental variables, we used the one previous observation
on x
it
, as shown in the text.
26
Table 11.12 presents the computations with several other
inconsistent estimators.
The various estimates are quite far apart. In the absence of the common effects (and
autocorrelation of the disturbances), all five estimators shown would be consistent. Given the
very wide disparities, one might suspect that common effects are an important feature of the
data. The second standard errors given with the IV estimates are based on the uncorrected
matrix in (11-73) with ˆσ
2
ε
in (11-74) divided by two. We found the estimator to be quite
volatile, as can be seen in the table. The estimator is also very sensitive to the choice of
instruments that comprise Z
i
. Using (11-71a) instead of (11-71b) produces wild swings in
the estimates and, in fact, produces implausible results. One possible explanation in this
particular example is that the instrumental variables we are using are dummy variables that
have relatively little variation over time.
26
This estimator and the GMM estimators in Chapter 13 are built into some contemporary computer programs,
including NLOGIT and Stata. Many researchers use Gauss programs that are distributed by M. Arellano,
http://www.cemfi.es/%7Earellano/#dpd, or program the calculations themselves using MatLab or R. We have
programmed the matrix computations directly for this application using the matrix package in NLOGIT.