
45O POLITICS IN THE EIGHTEENTH CENTURY
taxes on lands under its direct jurisdiction, in an effort to bring the
fruits of increasing agricultural productivity into its own ambit. The
result was an overall tax increase, by no means uniform across the
breadth of its holdings but, rather, varying from village to village.
From 1724 onward, a new taxation rate was hammered out in discus-
sion among the intendants, finance officials, and farmers. Those vil-
lages agreeing to the new rate were offered, in return, assessment by a
new system. Previously, each year's harvest had been estimated by
groups of traveling officials, who had to be courted and entertained -
and not infrequently bribed - by those villages they passed through.
Now, as an incentive to securing agreement to a higher tax rate, the
shogunate offered farming villages a permanently fixed assessment set
at a notional figure, thereby offering an escape from the nuisance of an
annual inspector and the sometimes-arbitrary exactions that accompa-
nied the older system. With this carrot-and-stick approach, the govern-
ment hoped first to raise, and then to stabilize, its land-tax income.
35
There were other changes as well. Formerly, people on bakufu land
in western Japan had been allowed to declare one-third of their hold-
ings as upland (and therefore unsuitable for growing rice), a technical-
ity that allowed them to pay one-third of their taxes in cash rather than
in rice, but now the custom was revised. In 1722 the bakufu decreed
that in principle all land taxes should be paid in rice, and it instructed
intendants to set rates as high as possible - higher even than the local
cost of rice - when farmers requested permission to pay in cash. This
in fact was another way of increasing taxes, as the farmers of western
Japan were known to prefer growing such lucrative cash crops as
tobacco, cotton, and rapeseed.
36
Through such means the shogunate managed to increase its tax
income considerably in 1727 and 1728. Between 1716 and 1723, its
average annual income from the land tax had been 1.37 million koku;
between 1724 and 1730 it rose to 1.52 million koku, an increase of
nearly 11 percent.
37
In 1727, particularly, the land-tax income of 1.62
million koku represented an increase of 320,000 koku over 1723, when
only 1.3 million koku had been collected.
38
35 Mori Sugio, "Kinsei chosaho no tenkan," in Osaka furilsu daigaku kiyo (Jimbun, shakai
kagaku 12) (1964), pp. 169-94; Tsuji, Kyoho, pp. 162-72.
36 Oishi, Kyoho, pp. 122-60.
37 These figures are taken from Otorika tsuji kakitsuke, which provides a reliable annual break-
down of bakufu finances over the period 1716 to 1841. See Tsuji Tatsuya and Matsumoto
Shiro,
"Otorika tsuji kakitsuke oyobi Onengu-mai, onengukin hoka shomuki osame watashi
kakitsuke ni tsuite," Yokohama shiritsu daigaku
ronso
(Jimbun kagaku keiretsu 15) (March
1964),
pp. 181-216.
38 Tsuji, Kyoho, pp. 173-5-
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008