
164 coalition government
viability. The important point here is how the explanation works. Note that Axelrod’s
account only relies on the number of parties, their seat share, and their ideological
position. From the perspective of the theory, other aspects of the cabinet formation
process are irrelevant, e.g. who can propose governments, how long the process can
last. Some disregard of existing structure, of course, is the essence of formal modeling.
The question is whether such a stripped-down model of government formation
explains the empirical phenomena. To rephrase the famous quote by Einstein: models
should be as simple as possible, but not simpler.
The answer to this question is, of course, empirical. Are there phenomena that
cannot be explained with an institution-free approach? Before the institutional shift
in the early 1990s much of the empirical study of government coalitions was focused
on one issue: the question of government formation. That is, suppose we know the
number of parties, their seat shares, and (in some models) their ideological position,
which governments would form?
4
The success of this research program was mixed.
Although it consisted of a fruitful interplay of theoretical and empirical work, all told,
institution-free models failed to predict which governments would form.
Two roots in the literature helped introduce institutionalist models into the study
of government coalitions. The first root was empirical. Specifically, two independent
empirical traditions played a critical role: Kaare Strom’s work on minority cabinets
and Browne et al.’s study of cabinet stability. The second root was theoretical and
consistent in the development of institutionalist models of cabinet formation (Laver
and Shepsle 1990;Baron1989).
Strom’s work (1985, 1990) was important in various respects. First, it focused on
a puzzling, but prevalent, case of coalition governments: minority governments,
i.e. cabinets where the parties that occupy portfolios together do not control a ma-
jority of seats in the legislature. As Strom pointed out, their existence is neither rare
(roughly a third of all coalition governments are of the minority type), nor does it
constitute a crisis phenomenon. Denmark, for example, is almost always governed by
minority governments, but hardly qualifies as a polity in crisis. Moreover, many of
the minority governments are surprisingly stable.
The existence of minority governments constituted an embarrassment for existing
theories of coalition formation. Why don’t the opposition parties that constitute
a chamber majority simply replace the incumbent minority government by a new
cabinet that includes them?
The influence of Strom’s work, however, went beyond the mere recognition of
minority governments. It had important methodological consequences for the study
of coalition governments in general. First, it refocused the government forma-
tion question from “which government will form?” to “which type of government
will form?”
5
That is, what are the factors that lead some countries regularly to
choose minority cabinets (e.g. Denmark), while others (e.g. Germany) almost always
choose minimum winning coalitions, while yet others (e.g. Italy) frequently choose
⁴ See e.g. Laver and Schofield 1990 for a detailed overview of this literature.
⁵ See, however, Martin and Stevenson 2001 for a recent, institutional, empirical study of coalition
formation that tried to answer the first question.