
maximization in favor of a strategy of long-term goals – a process very much in contrast
with the pressures on American managers to maximize short-term gains. Moreover, the
patterns of intercorporate stockholding also encourages many long-term business
relationships in Japan, which in turn reinforce ties of interdependence, exchange
relations, and reciprocal trust among firms’ (Hollingsworth, 1997: 280).* These kinds of
relationship have also led to low transaction costs among firms, high reliability of goods
supplied from one firm to another and close coordination of delivery schedule. ‘Because
Japanese trade associations are highly developed and span a variety of suppliers, buyers,
and related industries, they too have played an important role in developing cooperation
among competing and complementary firms, as well as in facilitating the clustering of
industries’ (Hollingsworth, 1997: 283).*
‘Having the option to develop long-term strategies, large Japanese firms have had the
ability to develop the kind of long-term relations with their employees, on which invest-
ment in worker training and flexible specialization are built’ (Hollingsworth, 1997:
280).* Inter-corporate ties explain that many large firms – particularly in steel, ship-
building and other heavy industries – have been able to shift employees to other
companies within their industrial group during economic downturns rather than dis-
missing the workers altogether. Moreover, firms with long-term job security have the
capacity to implement a seniority-based wage and promotion system, which in turn, pro-
motes employee motivation and identification with the company. Long-term job security
also enables the implementation of a system of job rotation (in work teams) and flexible
job assignments, and intensive in-firm instruction and on-the-job training. In addition,
however, lifetime employment combined with seniority pay, involves a high degree of
employee dependence on the firm. Indeed, since all large firms recruit externally only for
positions at the bottom of the job hierarchy and train their specialists for better jobs
through on-the-job training and job rotation, there is no further possibility of advance-
ment outside that firm (Dohse et al., 1989). The unitary school system in Japan (see
Chapter 5 for an explanation), with its poorly developed system for providing practical or
vocational training, explains that Japanese firms offer this type of training. And, because
of the existence of long-term job security, employees and unions accept that training is
highly firm-specific and not very generalizable to other organizations. This, of course,
further increases inflexibility in the external labour market.
Moreover, as indicated, the Japanese industrial relations system is characterized by
company unions. Company unions constitute a much more advantageous arena of nego-
tiations for management than more comprehensive unions. The ties of company unions to
the individual company makethem much more strongly dependent on market success, and
hence the productivity and cost structure of their firm. As a consequence, the scope of
labour union demands is restricted; conflictual goals with respect to the utilization of
labour (i.e. working conditions) are avoided in favour of positions that can be of benefit to
both sides. This pacification function, which is inherent in the structure of the company
union, was stabilized in the 1950s through destruction of the militant unions. The inten-
sive labour struggles of the 1950s were a decisive phase in the constitution of the current
MANAGING RESOURCES: PRODUCTION MANAGEMENT 339
* Hollingsworth, R. (1997) Continuities and changes in social systems of production: the cases of Japan,
Germany, and the United States. In Contemporary Capitalism: the Embeddedness of Institutions, edited by J. Rogers
Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press © J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert
Boyer 1997, reproduced with permission of the author and publisher.
MG9353 ch07.qxp 10/3/05 8:45 am Page 339