
chapter ten • pure monopoly 269
percentage has declined from 80
percent in the mid-1980s and
continues to shrink. Therein lies
De Beers’ problem.
Classic Monopoly Behaviour
De Beers’ past monopoly behav-
iour and results are a classic ex-
ample of the unregulated mo-
nopoly model illustrated in Figure
10-4. No matter how many dia-
monds it mined or purchased, De
Beers sold only that quantity of
diamonds that would yield an ap-
propriate (monopoly) price. That
price was well above production
costs, and De Beers and its part-
ners earned monopoly profits.
When demand fell, De Beers
reduced it sales to maintain price.
The excess of production over
sales was then reflected in grow-
ing diamond stockpiles held by
De Beers. It also attempted to
bolster demand through adver-
tising (“Diamonds are forever”).
When demand was strong, it in-
creased sales by reducing its dia-
mond inventories.
De Beers used several meth-
ods to control the production of
many mines it did not own. First,
it convinced a number of inde-
pendent producers that single-
channel or monopoly marketing
through De Beers would maxi-
mize their profit. Second, mines
that circumvented De Beers
often found their market sud-
denly flooded with similar dia-
monds from De Beers’ vast
stockpiles. The resulting price
decline and loss of profit often
would encourage the “rogue”
mine into the De Beers fold. Fi-
nally, De Beers simply pur-
chased and stockpiled diamonds
produced by independent mines
so their added supplies would
not undercut the market.
An End of an Era?
Several factors have come to-
gether to unravel the monopoly.
New diamond discoveries re-
sulted in a growing leakage of
diamonds into world markets
outside De Beers’ control. For
example, significant prospecting
and trading in Angola occurred.
Recent diamond discoveries in
Canada’s Northwest Territories
pose another threat. Although
De Beers is a participant in that
region, a large uncontrolled sup-
ply of diamonds is expected to
emerge. Similarly, although Rus-
sia is part of the De Beers’ mo-
nopoly, this cash-strapped coun-
try is allowed to sell part of its
diamond stock directly into the
world markets.
As if that were not enough,
Australian diamond producer
Argyle opted to withdraw from
the De Beers monopoly. Its an-
nual production of mostly low-
grade industrial diamonds ac-
counts for about 6 percent of the
global $8 billion diamond mar-
ket. The international media has
begun to focus heavily on the
role that diamonds play in fi-
nancing the bloody civil wars in
Africa. Fearing a consumer boy-
cott of diamonds, De Beers has
pledged not to buy these conflict
diamonds or do business with
any firms that does. These dia-
monds, however, continue to
find their way into the market-
place, eluding De Beers’ control.
In mid-2000 De Beer’s aban-
doned its attempt to control the
supply of diamonds. It an-
nounced that it planned to trans-
form itself from a diamond cartel
to a modern firm selling premium
diamonds and other luxury goods
under the De Beers label. It, there-
fore, would gradually reduce its
$4 billion stockpile of diamonds
and turn its efforts to increasing
the overall demand for diamonds
through advertising. De Beers
proclaimed that it was changing
its strategy to being “the dia-
mond supplier of choice.”
With its high market share
and ability to control its own
production levels, De Beers will
still wield considerable influence
over the price of rough-cut dia-
monds, but it turns out that the
De Beers monopoly was not
forever.