
Mutual aid, or help from within a group of like-minded people, was widely
practised over a wide range of working-class activity in towns and cities. Among
the working class it originated as a barrier against poverty and as a route to self-
help and some degree of financial security and personal welfare. Not thrust upon
them by other groups, it involved a collective strength absent from the middle-
class pursuit of self-help by individual enterprise.
Particularly prominent were friendly societies. They provided a means of
insuring against illness, old age and death, with weekly allowances when ill,
funeral payment to widows and medical attendance received in return for weekly
contributions, often made at convivial meetings in public houses. There was a
substantial number of local societies in the early nineteenth century (, in
), but the key feature between and was the growth of affiliated
orders of local societies, providing greater financial stability and viability. By
there were about . million members of friendly societies in Britain,
mostly in urban areas, such as those in Lancashire where relatively high wages
allowed workers to afford contributions. While both of the main affiliated orders
originated in south-east Lancashire, the Oddfellows were strongest in the indus-
trial North, and the Ancient Order of Foresters, with flexible rates of contribu-
tion and benefit, attracted members in lower wage areas in southern England.
34
Trade unions also provided collective self-help with pay for strikes, sickness
and unemployment for about , members in . After major
national unions, notably the Amalgamated Society of Engineers and the
Amalgamated Society of Carpenters and Joiners, developed among skilled arti-
sans, similar to the affiliated orders of friendly societies but including relief for
the unemployed. Yet, regional autonomy survived in the non-tramping trades
and trade union societies grew in the coalfields throughout the country and in
the three main centres of unionism in the earlier nineteenth century: London
with societies in a wide range of occupations, particularly artisan and riverside
trades; the Lancashire cotton industry; and the sailors and shipwrights in the
north-eastern coal trade.
35
The pattern of union membership with its access to
unemployment pay could reflect the local economy where there was a marked
cyclical pattern as in shipbuilding. Similarly, the Co-operative movement, with
between , and , members in , was especially successful in
medium-size towns in the textile districts (the biggest societies were in Halifax,
Leeds, Bury and Rochdale), the mining villages of North-East England and the
shoe and hosiery districts of the East Midlands where there were relatively stable
earnings; they were less successful both in large centres, especially London and
Birmingham where small workshop employment predominated, and in low-paid
The provision of social services
34
Finlayson, Citizen, State and Social Welfare, pp. –; M. Purvis, ‘Popular institutions’, in J. Langton
and R. J. Morris, eds., Atlas of Industrialising Britain, – (London, ), pp. –.
35
Finlayson, Citizen, State and Social Welfare, p. ; H. Southall, ‘Unionisation’, in Langton and
Morris, eds., Atlas, pp. –.
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008