very few firms that could actually use the products of these so-called ‘cathedrals in the
desert’ in the manufacture of final goods.
Insofar as the state’s investments in productive enterprises almost always involved
heavy industry, the industrial geography of Italy began to change noticeably after the
1960s. The heavy industries owned by the State, particularly steel (IRI) and
petrochemicals (ENI, the national hydrocarbons firm), came to dominate investment,
employment and output in the previously underdeveloped South. At the same time, inputs
from these firms fed into the large-scale mass production enterprises of the northwest,
which were mainly in the hands of family capital that had begun to realize the advantages
of stock market shares for expanding their enterprises. The small and medium-sized firms
of the northeast and central parts of Italy benefited from tax incentives and export
subsidies, but had to remain flexibly specialized in order to compete on world markets.
This situation has been defined as the phenomenon of the ‘Three Italics’.
Even though investments in the South had been quite high through the 1980s, a
fundamental flaw in the mechanisms chosen for national and regional economic growth
was that the Mezzogiorno did not achieve an autonomous capacity for sustained
industrial development. Ironically, at the very time that certain areas in southern Italy
were becoming used to the idea of being industrial, a process of tertiarization of the
economy, if not a full-blown deindustrialization, had begun. Simultaneously, the weak
equity market in Italy made it difficult for the large-scale family firms in the northwest to
float financial offerings to raise capital, and globalization made the going tougher for the
export-led growth sector of the northeast and centre. Industrial restructuring and
readjustment programmes, often painful for entire regions, were decisively implemented,
and thus by the mid1990s a whole new pattern of industrial development was underway.
The new model saw massive privatization, some closures of state participation
enterprises, a restructuring of the mass production sector, an invigoration of the
competitive drive of flexibly specialized firms through the elimination of export
subsidies, and an opening up of the Italian market to more foreign products (see also
privatization and nationalization). But privatization was only in part a response to
industrial problems; there was also a political dimension (albeit with economic
overtones). The European Union, via its commissions, had come to question the role
played by state enterprises in inhibiting trade and competition among the firms of
member states (see Masi, 1996). While Italy was not the only country with such holdings,
in the 1980s its state participation sector was by far the largest in Europe outside of the
then communist bloc. In fact, in its heyday the state participation sector employed nearly
three quarters of a million people and was engaged in activities that covered iron and
steel, cement, engineering, shipbuilding, hydrocarbons, chemicals, textiles and other
manufacturing. The holdings also extended into the service sector, including airlines,
highways, shipping, radio and telephones.
Privatization of the state participation sector was supposed to be an ongoing effort. In
the original mandate of the IRI, for example, individual firms, once placed back on a
solid financial and productive footing, were to be returned to private hands. Occasionally
this was done, but for the most part, until the mid-1980s, the state participation sector
grew rapidly, sometimes by continuing ‘salvaging’ operations and sometimes by creating
wholly new enterprises. The latter involved sectors into which private capital either could
not venture, because of high costs or simply would not, due to perceived high risks.
Entries A–Z 401