
124 woodruff d. smith
standard Marxist and modernization-based approaches. So strong were those assump-
tions as late as the early 1980s that Paul Kennedy, in his excellent study of the origins
of the antagonism between Britain and Germany before World War I, after having
made what many readers believed to be a good case for understanding that antago-
nism in largely political and ideological terms, concluded by ascribing it on much
weaker grounds to economic competition.
11
Since then, historians have been more
willing to challenge both the notion that the orgy of competitive imperial expansion
in which the European powers indulged at the turn of the century was a direct
product of economic change and the idea that it was caused mainly by class conflict
at home (the concept of “social imperialism” mentioned above.)
“Political” can mean many things, of course. It can include the kind of struc-
tural–diplomatic interpretation that ascribes pre-1914 imperialism to the collapse of
the system created at the Congress of Vienna and to the decline of British global
hegemony in the late nineteenth century – both in large part due to the sudden
rise of the unified German Reich as a great power.
12
In recent years, historians of
imperialism who emphasize diplomacy have tended to focus less on such structural
factors and more on the mindsets of those who discussed and made policy in the
major imperialist states. In some cases, this takes the form of analyzing the ways
politicians and bureaucrats understood (and misunderstood) what they were doing.
13
In others, the focus of attention is broader, encompassing the array of conceptions
present in the public discourse in the major European countries regarding trends in
the wider world.
A particularly useful way to look at the aggressive imperialism of the turn of the
century from a political angle is to connect it to the changes in the political structure,
behavior, and culture of European states that are collectively called “democratization”
– changes that occurred even in places like imperial Germany that were not, in an
institutional sense, democracies. The term refers not just to a broadening of the
franchise but also to a vast expansion of participation in the public sphere, a prolifera-
tion of interest groups vying to influence public opinion, the appearance of mass
political parties, and a host of other alterations in the political scene. The relationship
between democratization and imperialism was actually a subject of considerable dis-
cussion at the time among politicians and commentators. It was never wholly ignored
by historians after 1918. Only fairly recently, however, has it become a central focus
of attention among scholars interested in the ways participants in modern political
systems seek to establish broad bases of support by creating ideological, discursive,
and iconic linkages between their particular agendas and broad social and cultural
patterns. In the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, imperialism served as
a device with which politicians, state officials, leaders of interest groups, journalists –
indeed, people of all sorts who took an active part in politics – attempted to operate
within democratizing political systems that seemed newly complex and bewildering.
Very often, the economic reasoning that plays so large a role in standard interpreta-
tions of imperialism reflected not so much the realities faced by businesses functioning
in global markets, or even policy problems handled by governments, as it did the
expectations of the various audiences that made up the public spheres of the imperial-
ist countries. This helps to explain why so many of the new colonies acquired by
European states around the turn of the century had so little economic relevance to
their occupiers and why the occupiers turned to development schemes that were