
io6 6 SYRIA AND THE EAST
to some form of tribute. Thus it is possible that ancient local structures
survived under the Seleucids (and perhaps even developed towards
political forms of autonomy) but that, in property relationships and on
the economic level in general, landowners were imposed or super-
imposed upon these communities from above (through the institution
of the royal gift estate
(dorea))
and that they were thereby entitled to exact
a tax on what the communities produced.
It is immediately apparent that agriculture is the basic form of
production in the Seleucid kingdom and that the royal estates constitute
a particularly large and certainly the most important form of property.
From the flat river valleys of Syria to the plain of Mesopotamia, the
scattered peripheral plains and high plateaux of Iran, where cultivation
of the soil or pasturage was practicable, the fertile lands of Cilicia, it is
possible to indicate the geographical contexts we must presuppose for
the royal estates and for the
laoi,
that is the peasant population, which
lived on the land and worked it. But we have only partial knowledge of
the organization of such estates: the specific terminology, an important
clue to organization, appears mainly in inscriptions; but inscriptions
containing important indications concerning both terminology and
organization come mainly,
as
we have seen, from western Asia Minor. In
these texts we find the terms describing types of habitat: the
kome,
that is,
the village; the
ban's,
that is, probably, the farm (possibly with some
fortification
—
in a sense a villa); the
epaulis
(perhaps meaning something
similar); rather more general, but still describing a rural place, the
chorion
or topos. Then we find terms indicating the inhabitants or, more
specifically, their social condition: the
laoi,
the
oiketai;
terms relative to
types of cultivation:
paradeisoi
(orchards), etc. This is the fundamental
form of property which fits into an historical tradition of social and
economic relations belonging specifically to Asia, characterized by the
presence of an absolute master (in this case the king
(basileus))
and a
dependent population
{laoi),
among whom there can occasionally exist
conditions of actual slavery, though this does not seem to be the norm.
But besides this type of agrarian property, there are certainly others,
such as the great private estate, which was perhaps thought of merely as
a concession from the king who 'suspended' his rights in favour of his
proteges (important people in the kingdom, people the king wished to
reward or favourites, or perhaps ancient landowners) to whom he ceded
his right of possession or title to the property. There were also (in Syria,
Babylonia, Iran, Cilicia and the inner regions of western Asia Minor) all
the temple possessions, which made up a conspicuous part of the
Seleucid territory: lands with their villages annexed to sanctuaries, and
with a population which would provide the indispensable personnel to
serve the sanctuaries
[hierodouloi).
These estates were organized struc-
Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008