
Moreover, the unitary board system, combined with the threat of take-over, helps to
explain the difficulty of the Anglo-Saxon system with aligning the interests of private
investors and corporations with those of society as a whole, including employees, suppliers
and local communities. Indeed, the market for corporate control often disregards its effects
on both human and social capital. Short-term capital is also argued to contribute to
impeding the creation of the organizational competencies necessary for firms competing
in sectors characterized by incremental innovation processes (Streeck, 1992). In other
words, the system fails to encourage sufficient investment to secure competitive posi-
tions in existing business. It also induces investments in the wrong forms. It heavily
favours acquisitions, which involve assets that can easily be valued, over internal develop-
ment projects that are more difficult to value and that constitute a drag on current
earnings (Porter, 1997).
Major strengths of the Rhineland model are that it encourages investment to upgrade
capabilities and productivity in existing fields; it also encourages internal diversification
into related fields – the kind of diversification that builds on and extends corporate
strengths. The Rhineland model comes closer to optimizing long-term private and social
returns. The focus on long-term corporate position – encouraged by an ownership struc-
ture and governance process that, together, incorporate the interests of employees,
suppliers, customers and the local community – allows the German economy to utilize
more successfully the social benefits of private investment (Porter, 1997: 12–13).
Downsides of the Rhineland model, however, are the tendency to over-invest in capacity,
to produce too many products, and to maintain unprofitable businesses. Moreover, the
stable, long-term relationships between banks and firms are increasingly seen as
inhibiting the formation and growth of firms in new sectors. As indicated above, the long-
term stable shareholder relationships typical of the Rhineland model impede the
development of a large, liquid capital market. A large capital market is critical for risk
capital or venture capital providers, as it creates a viable ‘exit option’ via initial public
offering (IPO) and mergers or acquisitions (Casper, 1999). Without this exit option, it is
difficult for venture capitalists to diversify risks across several investments and to create a
viable refinancing mechanism.
The comparative approach of this chapter helps reveal the fact that there is no such
a thing as a ‘perfect’ or the ‘best’ system. While, at present, the majority view is that the
shareholder model will prevail due to the increasing dominance of institutional investors
on international capital markets (Lazonick and O’Sullivan, 2000), the intense and
ongoing competition between the Anglo-Saxon and the Rhineland models in Europe pro-
vides evidence to counter this argument. The impact of this competition provides few
signs of change in the UK and only small step-changes, incorporating some elements of
the Anglo-Saxon model into the ‘large firm’ Rhineland model in Germany. Since national
forms of corporate governance are embedded in established ‘practices’ and ‘regulatory
policies’, change in one area does not involve a change in the entire system.
In fact, as the example of Germany shows, modifications of the existing approach to
corporate governance that accommodate the new circumstances are more likely. Real
change would require root-and-branch change, and as there is not even a consensus on
the need for change, let alone a consensus on what that change should be, root-and-
branch change in both the UK and Germany – the European representatives of the two
strongest models of corporate governance – has not yet occured, and is unlikely to. Hence,
296 COMPARATIVE INTERNATIONAL MANAGEMENT
MG9353 ch06.qxp 10/3/05 8:45 am Page 296