
5.3 • Comparative statics
375
where I denotes investment, which is assumed to be given by
I = I* (3)
for some constant I*. Equations (1), (2) and (3) describe the structure of the model and as such
are called structural equations. Substituting equations (1) and (3) into equation (2) gives
Y = aY + b + I*
Y − aY = b + I* (subtract aY from both sides)
(1 − a)Y = b + I* (take out a common factor of Y )
Y = (divide both sides by 1 − a)
This is known as the reduced form because it compresses the model into a single equation
in which the endogenous variable, Y, is expressed in terms of the exogenous variable, I*, and
parameters, a and b. The process of analysing the equilibrium level of income in this way is
referred to as statics because it assumes that the equilibrium state is attained instantaneously.
The branch of mathematical economics which investigates time dependence is known as
dynamics and is considered in Chapter 9.
We should like to do rather more than just to calculate the equilibrium values here. In par-
ticular, we are interested in the effect on the endogenous variables in a model brought about
by changes in the exogenous variables and parameters. This is known as comparative statics,
since we seek to compare the effects obtained by varying each variable and parameter in turn.
The actual mechanism for change will be ignored and it will be assumed that the system returns
to equilibrium instantaneously. The equation
Y =
shows that Y is a function of three variables, a, b and I*, so we can write down three partial
derivatives
,,
The only hard one to work out is the first, and this is found using the chain rule by writing
Y = (b + I*)(1 − a)
−1
which gives
= (b + I*)(−1)(1 − a)
−2
(−1) =
To interpret this derivative let us suppose that the marginal propensity to consume, a, changes
by ∆a with b and I* held constant. The corresponding change in Y is given by
∆Y =∆a
Strictly speaking, the ‘=’ sign should really be ‘’. However, as we have seen in the previous two
sections, provided that ∆a is small the approximation is reasonably accurate. In any case we
could argue that the model itself is only a first approximation to what is really happening in the
economy and so any further small inaccuracies that are introduced are unlikely to have any
significant effect on our conclusions. The above equation shows that the change in national
income is found by multiplying the change in the marginal propensity to consume by the par-
tial derivative ∂Y/∂a. For this reason the partial derivative is called the marginal propensity to
consume multiplier for Y. In the same way, ∂Y/∂b and ∂Y/∂I* are called the autonomous con-
sumption multiplier and the investment multiplier, respectively.
∂Y
∂a
b + I*
(1 − a)
2
∂Y
∂a
∂Y
∂I*
∂Y
∂b
∂Y
∂a
b + I*
1 − a
b + I*
1 − a
MFE_C05c.qxd 16/12/2005 10:41 Page 375