
chapter eight • the organization and the costs of production 209
chapter summary
1. The firm is the most efficient form of organ-
izing production and distribution. The main
goal of a firm is to maximize profit.
2. Sole proprietorships, partnerships, and cor-
porations are the major legal forms that busi-
ness enterprises may assume. Though
proprietorships dominate numerically, the
bulk of total output is produced by corpora-
tions. Corporations have grown to their posi-
tion of dominance in the business sector
primarily because they are characterized by
limited liability and can acquire money capi-
tal for expansion more easily than other
firms can.
3. Economic costs include all payments that
must be received by resource owners to
ensure a continued supply of needed re-
sources to a particular line of production.
Economic costs include explicit costs, which
flow to resources owned and supplied by
others, and implicit costs, which are pay-
ments for the use of self-owned and self-
employed resources. One implicit cost is a
normal profit to the entrepreneur. Economic
profit occurs when total revenue exceeds
total cost (= explicit costs + implicit costs,
including a normal profit).
4. In the short run a firm’s plant capacity is
fixed. The firm can use its plant more or less
intensively by adding or subtracting units of
various resources, but it does not have suffi-
cient time in the short run to alter plant size.
5. The law of diminishing returns describes
what happens to output as a fixed plant is
used more intensively. As successive units
of a variable resource such as labour are
added to a fixed plant, beyond some point
the marginal product associated with each
additional worker declines.
6. Because some resources are variable and
others are fixed, costs can be classified
as variable or fixed in the short run. Fixed
costs are independent of the level of output;
recouped once it has been paid.
A firm’s decision about whether
to move from the store to a more
profitable location does not de-
pend on the amount of time re-
maining on the lease. If moving
means greater profit, it makes
sense to move whether there are
300 days, 30 days, or 3 days left
on the lease.
Or, as another example, sup-
pose a firm spends $1 million on
R&D to bring out a new product,
only to discover that the product
sells very poorly. Should the firm
continue to produce the product
at a loss even when there is no
realistic hope for future success?
Obviously, it should not. In mak-
ing this decision, the firm real-
izes that the amount it has spent
in developing the product is irrel-
evant; it should stop production
of the product and cut its losses.
In fact, many firms have dropped
products after spending millions
of dollars on their development.
Examples are the quick decision
by Coca-Cola to drop its New
Coke and the eventual decision
by McDonald’s to drop its
McLean Burger.
Consider a final real-world ex-
ample. For decades, Boeing and
McDonnell Douglas were keen
rivals in the worldwide sale of
commercial airplanes. Each com-
pany spent billions of dollars on
R&D and marketing in an at-
tempt to gain competitive ad-
vantages over each other. Then,
in 1996 they suddenly merged.
Many observers wondered how
two fierce rivals who had spent
such huge amounts to compete
could suddenly forget the past
and agree to merge. But these
past efforts and expenditures
were irrelevant to the decision;
they were sunk costs. The for-
ward-looking decision led both
companies to conclude, each for
its own reasons, that the mar-
ginal benefit of a merger would
outweigh the marginal cost.
In short, if a cost has been in-
curred and cannot be partly or
fully recouped by some other
choice, a rational consumer or
firm should ignore it. Sunk costs
are irrelevant. Or, as the saying
goes, don’t cry over spilt milk.