
exceeds its marginal cost because the firm would gain more in revenue from selling
that unit than it would add to its costs by producing it. Conversely, if the marginal
cost of a unit of output exceeds its marginal revenue, the firm will not produce that
unit. Producing it would add more to costs than to revenue and profit would
decline or loss would increase.
MR = MC RULE
In the initial stages of production, where output is relatively low, marginal revenue
will usually (but not always) exceed marginal cost. So it is profitable to produce
through this range of output. But at later stages of production, where output is rel-
atively high, rising marginal costs will exceed marginal revenue. Obviously, a profit-
maximizing firm will want to avoid output levels in that range. Separating these
two production ranges is a unique point at which marginal revenue equals marginal
cost. This point is the key to the output-determining rule: In the short run, the firm will
maximize profit or minimize loss by producing the output at which marginal revenue equals
marginal cost. This profit-maximizing guide is known as the MR = MC rule. (For
most sets of MR and MC data, MR and MC will be precisely equal at a fractional
level of output. In such instances the firm should produce the last complete unit of
output for which MR exceeds MC.)
THREE CHARACTERISTICS OF THE MR = MC RULE
Keep in mind these three features of the MR = MC rule:
1. The rule applies only if producing is preferable to shutting down. We will show
shortly that if marginal revenue does not equal or exceed average variable cost,
the firm will prefer to shut down rather than produce the MR = MC output.
2. The rule is an accurate guide to profit maximization for all firms whether they are
purely competitive, monopolistic, monopolistically competitive, or oligopolistic.
3. The rule can be restated as P = MC when applied to a purely competitive firm.
Because the demand schedule faced by a competitive seller is perfectly elastic at
the going market price, product price and marginal revenue are equal. So under
pure competition (and only under pure competition) we may substitute P for MR
in the rule; when producing is preferable to shutting down, the competitive firm should
produce at that point where price equals marginal cost (P = MC).
Now let’s apply the MR = MC rule or, because we are considering pure competition,
the P = MC rule, first using the same price as in our total-revenue–total-cost approach
to profit maximization. Then, by considering other prices, we will demonstrate two
additional cases: loss minimization and shut down. It is crucial that you understand the
MR = MC analysis that follows since it reappears in Chapters 10 and 11.
PROFIT-MAXIMIZING CASE
The first five columns in Table 9-4 reproduce the AFC, AVC, ATC, and MC data
derived for our product in Table 8-2. It is the marginal-cost data of column 5 that we
will compare with price (equals marginal revenue) for each unit of output. Suppose
first that the market price, and therefore marginal revenue, is $131, as shown in
column 6.
What is the profit-maximizing output? Every unit of output up to and including
the ninth unit represents greater marginal revenue than marginal cost of output.
Each of the first nine units, therefore, adds to the firm’s profit and will be produced.
chapter nine • pure competition 221
mr = mc
rule
A method
of determining the
total output at
which economic
profit is at a maxi-
mum (or losses at
a minimum).