
Hourly wage rates and annual salaries differ greatly among occupations. In Table
15-3 we list average weekly wages for several industries to illustrate such occupational
wage differentials. For example, observe that construction workers on average earn
almost a third more than those workers in the health and service industry. Large wage
differentials also exist within some of the occupations listed (not shown). For example,
although average wages for retail salespersons are relatively low, some top salesper-
sons selling on commission make several times the average wages for their occupation.
What explains wage differentials such as these? Once again, the forces of demand and
supply are revealing. As we demonstrate in Figure 15-9, wage differentials can arise on
either the supply or demand side of labour markets. Figures 15-9(a) and (b) represent
labour markets for two occupational groups that have identical labour supply curves. The
labour market in panel a has a relatively high equilibrium wage (W
a
) because labour
demand is very strong. The labour market in panel b has an equilibrium wage that is rel-
atively low (W
b
) since labour demand is weak. Clearly, the wage differential between
occupations (a) and (b) results solely from differences in the magnitude of labour demand.
Contrast that situation with Figure 15-9(c) and (d), where the labour demand
curves are identical. In the labour market in panel (c), the equilibrium wage is rela-
tively high (W
c
) because labour supply is highly restricted. In the labour market in
panel (d) labour supply is highly abundant, so the equilibrium wage (W
d
) is rela-
tively low. The wage differential between (c) and (d) results solely from the differ-
ences in the magnitude of the labour supply.
Although Figure 15-9 provides a good starting point for understanding wage dif-
ferentials, we need to know why demand and supply conditions differ in various
labour markets.
Marginal Revenue Productivity
The strength of labour demand—how far rightward
the labour demand curve is located—differs greatly
among occupations because of differences in how
much various occupational groups contribute to
their employers’ revenue. This revenue contribution,
in turn, depends on the workers’ productivity and
the strength of the demand for the products they are
helping to produce. Where labour is highly produc-
tive and product demand is strong, labour demand
also is strong, and other things equal, pay is high.
Top professional athletes, for example, are highly
productive at sports entertainment, for which mil-
lions of people are willing to pay billions of dollars
over the course of a season. So the marginal revenue
productivity of these top players is exceptionally
high, as are their salaries, represented in Figure
15-9(a). In contrast, in most occupations workers
generate much more modest revenue for their
employers, so their pay is lower, as in Figure 15-9(b).
Noncompeting Groups
On the supply side of the labour market, workers
are not homogeneous; they differ in their mental
chapter fifteen • wage determination, discrimination, and immigration 393
Wage Differentials
wage differ-
entials
The
difference between
the wage received
by one worker or
group of workers
and that received by
another worker or
group of workers.
TABLE 15-3 AVERAGE
WEEKLY WAGES
IN SELECTED
INDUSTRIES, 2000
Average weekly
earnings
(including
Industry overtime)
All industries $ 626.45
Mining, quarrying, and oil wells 1,152.60
Logging and forestry 821.23
Transportation, storage,
communications, and other utilities 779.32
Manufacturing 778.30
Finance, insurance, and real estate 777.52
Construction 722.84
Educational and related services 672.88
Health and social services 542.25
Trade 476.48
Source: Statistics Canada, <www.statcan.ca/english/Pgdb>.
Visit www.mcgrawhill.ca/college/mcconnell9 for data update.
marginal
revenue
productivity
How much workers
contribute to their
employers’ revenue.